It is easier to tear down and destroy than it is to build and create. This is true whether we are talking about a tower of blocks, a work of art or a civilization. Our civilization will be stronger and more resilient when most people believe that we will all be better off when we seek to improve our society and the health of the ecosystem that sustains it. Ideally, each of us will appreciate and embrace the challenge of developing a promising and beneficent global civilization. If we strive to make a world that recognizes the people as the rightful owners of natural resource wealth, we will create a society that does not have more paving or pollution or noise or more rapid extraction of limited resources than what most people would say is acceptable.
A society that recognizes the people as rightful owners of the Earth's natural resources will not tolerate inequitable exploitation of this shared legacy. An owner of natural resources is one who has a right to use these resource--a right to share in the enjoyment of natural opportunities. So not just humans. An owner has a right to stop others from messing up the resource, and a right to receive compensation when damage is done or value taken. (Human beings are a life-form unique on the planet; unique in our ability to devastate ecosystems that sustain other lifeforms. Any sense within us that we have a right to use what we find in the environment and to enjoy the benefits of clean air and water, we must acknowledge a similar sense in our fellow inhabitants. If other lifeforms also have a right to share in the benefits of natural wealth, we need to limit how much we actually disturb the ecosystems that sustain them. We will do this when we recognize those rights and resolve to limit our disturbances so that they are held to levels that (most people agree) are respectful of the rights of our fellow Earthlings and are, therefore, also respectful of our conscience.
If fees are charged to those who use or mess up wealth of the commons (natural resources), the proceeds should go to the people. A guaranteed minimum income for everyone on Earth could result from the collection of fees for use of natural resources in agriculture, industry and commerce. A minimum income would decrease the problems associated with disparity of wealth and would end abject poverty, while the universal nature of such a payment would ensure that no one would forgo productive work for fear of loosing their public property dividend. As our economy becomes more fair and transparent, more people will come to feel an ownership in the system. They will be more likely to want to protect and improve rather than destroy. By making the least secure among us more secure, we will make everyone more secure.
Attaching fees to the use of natural resources would create a mechanism whereby citizens could exert their will on the larger economic system, to define appropriate limits to potentially harmful human activities. What levels of pollution and what rates of extraction of resources are acceptable? We could all share in deciding limits to human activities insofar as those activities impinge on the commons. If most people polled in a random survey say that they want stricter limits on the extent of monoculture or of paving or on release of a particular kind of pollution, for example, then the associated fee would increase, causing industries to try harder to reduce the offending activity. And the inverse is also true: Any activity that had been discouraged more strongly than the people now deemed necessary would have its associated fees reduced. The actual conditions on the Earth that result from the sum of all human activities would come to reflect the expressed will of the people, as reflected by random polls. (We can know that a poll is reliable and that it can serve as the basis of public policy if anyone is able to take a second poll and thereby verify the first one. Solid and reliable documentation of methodology could compliment (or substitute for) repeating a poll for verification purposes.)
In such a democratic society, we would not allow loss of biodiversity, pollution of our streams and rivers, high rates of mineral depletion, (including fossil fuels), loss of our starscape every night of the year to light pollution--at least, we would not allow these things beyond what is acceptable to the people. Given a voice in the management of natural resource wealth (which owners should have) we likely would not consent to the conditions in the world as we've made it thus far. When we fully apply our principles of ownership and fair compensation to questions of natural resource wealth management--when we recognize commons or public property rights in our accounting--much will change. We will have a synthesis of capitalism and communism in a truly democratic society. We will have a civilization that is sustainable or much more likely to be so. We will have a more just society.
Systemic flaws are not reported
Natural law requires that we respect public AND private property rights. Respect public property rights by limiting levels of pollution and rates of taking of resources to what most people feel is acceptable; and by sharing equally a monetary representation of natural resource wealth to all people.
Saturday, December 22, 2012
Wednesday, December 19, 2012
Critique of the Gaia Brain paradigm, a Biological Model for Politics and Economics
Title: Gaia Brain: Integration of Human Society and the Biosphere
Summary: On the basis of an analogy between how nonhuman organisms (from unicellular to bees) affect and are affected by their environment and how economic forces affect the use of natural resources, this paper proposes a radical transformation of human life: Children are to be educated differently, governments as they now exist will be abolished, and the labor market will be liberated from its current constraints.
The detrimental impact human beings have on the environment presents us with the "greatest challenge" the species has faced since it began to walk and talk. Economics provides the key to its solution: a "resource fee" that will be assessed to every product and service. These fees will penalize the use of environmentally damaging things, providing the "feedback mechanism" that is needed so that human culture will be in touch with its impact on the biosphere. This fee will provide the marketplace with information about the product's or service's environmental impact. They will be determined democratically by every person on the planet. Proceeds will be used to support "things we would like to see more of."
Evaluation: This paper is eminently clear; the author is able in a few paragraphs to present and weave together findings from microbiology, ethology, and economics into an intriguing and intelligible picture. On the basis of his assessment of the current "environmental crisis," he proposes an interesting (and to me, novel) solution. An effective way of affecting people's behavior is through their wallets, so charge them for the damage they are indirectly doing to the environment. The author also recognizes a number of problems which might be raised to this suggestion (Who determines the fees?, How will this money be used?, Etc.) and attempts in the limited space available to address them. Although, as proposed, this suggestion seems to be thoroughly unrealistic, there could be merits to its basic idea. Something like a "resource fee" might be worth considering as environmental policies are discussed.
The significant "leftist" tendencies of the paper weaken it. The author continues to have hopes in a world (non-) government, a radical transformation of society, a radical and universal democracy, and an elimination or significant reduction of alienation. His solutions to the problems inherent in his proposal seem weak. It is not clear to me that all people (including children -- p.7, ln.20) can ever be in a position to assess the conflicting "findings" of the "experts" of interested parties as to the true environmental impact of every product and service of every activity of every person and company of the whole world. And, without governments, how will the money be spent? Will every person on the planet have a say? How could that occur?
Recommendation: If a clear and interesting voice from those who continue to propose radical transformations of society and of human nature is needed, this paper could find a place in the proceedings. If the volume needs to be limited to realistic proposals, it does not belong.
-- End of this anonymous critique --
Author's response:
The idea of a pollution fee or fee on use of natural resource, the commons, is not new with me. I learned about it in a college text during a course on political economy, in a book called, 'The Economics of Social Issues'. What is new, to my knowledge, is the connection drawn between this method of management of resources and the feedback mechanisms that operate in biological organisms, such as sensory nervous systems. Also new is the (proposed) practical realization of the idea that all people share in the ownership and management of the air and water, the commons, the natural resources, by receiving the proceeds of the user-fees, and by deciding what absolute limits will be placed on the use of the resources.
I do not propose that a fee be assessed on 'every product or service', but on those human actions which adversely impact the environment. If I am a reading tutor and I ask a student to read to me and I give little hints when needed, I am providing a service, but I am not adversely impacting the Commons, and would not expect to have to pay the people to compensate them for degrading a public resource. If I drive 50 miles to get to the school, I expect to pay a fee to compensate the people for degrading their resource, the air, but payment of this fee would not be a separate act. The fee would be incorporated in the price of fuel by the fact that extracting petroleum for use as fuel would have the appropriate fee attached. If I take some kind of waste products and recycle them into new product, I would not expect to have to pay a fee. " ... [C]harge them for the damage they are indirectly doing to the environment", sounds like we would examine each life, each person and make an assessment, a judgement of their impact on the earth by recording their purchases or examining their habits. That does sound totally unrealistic. But that is not what I propose. I would rather charge the corporations that damage the earth or cause environmental impacts. If individuals damage environmental health in ways that are not already accounted for in prices through this fee mechanism, then charge individuals for the damage they do directly.
As a practical matter, if a material is produced and marketed for a particular application, such as petroleum for fuel, then the producer ought to be assessed at the point of production as if delivery to market was equivalent to actual use. This way, the market will reflect in price the (perceived) ecologic impact of use. I would judge, for example, the 'damage to the earth' as the act of taking oil out of the ground, where it can be easily measured, rather than have gasoline delivered to the market prior to the assessment of any impact fees, and assessing the fees on the end-user. Making the necessary measurements as close to the point of production as possible will reduce the potential for subversion through black market trading.
It would be easier for me to accept 'unrealistic ... radical transformation' as valid and true argument against this paradigm if not for the fact that this plan could help to alleviate or eliminate some of our society's seemingly most intractable problems. This possibility of multiple benefits through the realization of this new paradigm could overcome the resistance to change that usually makes radical change such an unrealistic possibility. If not now for radical transformation, when? We have just invented a whole new media: Interactive hypermedia; the internet. Perhaps soon, this new form of human communication will be as extensive as the telephone network, which also continues to expand. We are in the midst of a long period of accelerating change. It is in times of invention of new tools that we see the greatest social, political and economic changes, because they so affect the ways that human beings interact with one another.
The basic idea here, or basic ideas are that we all own the air and water and natural resources, and to the extent that any person or corporate entity appropriates any of these resources for their own use, that entity ought to compensate the owners of the resource, the people at large. The monies paid in exchange for the use of resources should be controlled by the people, who may use these funds for whatever purpose they choose, but perhaps with a portion dedicated to community projects that enjoy the support of a large majority of citizens, and the remaining portion available for individual needs and wants. The people also should control the level of the fee, or the overall rate of resource use: The people are owners and managers of the commons.
"Something like a resource fee..." What does this mean? What thing like a resource fee might we consider? How would this something be like a resource fee and how would it be different? (Who would decide on the fee amount? How would the proceeds be spent?)
What is meant by 'leftist' tendencies, and why is it in quotes? (I did not use the term in the paper.) Perhaps 'leftist' refers to the idea that all the people own and would help manage the commons, and would receive the proceeds of the fees charged against their use. Anecdotal evidence suggests that this idea is readily understood and accepted by members of the public who have been apprised of it. Many people feel that, yes, this is a good idea, but 'they', the established interests, will never go for it. To the extent that politicians, captains of industry and citizens successfully turn the purposes of government and corporate institutions toward these ends, they can help restore a sense of integrity and efficacy to our public institutions. This idea, put in practice, would reverse the trend toward greater disparity of wealth, while preserving, even improving, free market rewards of individual effort and initiative. It would help to promote a sense among the populace that we all share a power and responsibility to be good stewards of the earth. For these reasons, 'leftist' tendencies seems to be not a weakness, but a strength.
I did not intend to suggest that children would be responsible for making decisions regarding resource use. I do suggest though, that children, students, might be involved in the process of gathering information about the opinions of the adults in their neighborhood. But the reviewer's statement brings to mind the idea that some communities might choose to celebrate exceptional, exemplary schools that cast their own mock votes about what environmental impacts ought to be allowed with such careful consideration and clear explication of the why behind their votes that they stand as a model to others of how this responsibility for stewardship of the commons might be carried out. The community might want the school's mock votes published so that they can be copied by others, in effect letting the adults delegate their vote to those outstanding students.
We could ask someone from a trusted accounting firm (or someone who knows more about accounting principles than I) how we might make scalable structures, accounts of each person's preferences, then each community's preferences, etc. that could be surveyed at any level, just as search engines survey large amounts of data through a network. The example of the school above may offer a clue to how this might be done. If teachers and students made it their business to ask community members what their opinions are about conditions in the community, they could post the results of their surveys on the internet for all to see. To the extent that the expressed wishes of the people conflict with actual conditions, we would expect resource user-fees to rise or fall as appropriate, until the disparity is resolved.
What better time to consider and make radical transformations than now? These are times of rapid, accelerating change, when the situation is dynamic and plastic, when we can make a great difference for the future depending on what decisions we take today, what we do today. A radical transformation, in the right direction, could be a very helpful and timely change.
But what change in human nature does the reviewer believe is required by this proposal? If anything, this paradigm is more respectful, more accepting of human nature as it is. The current system has a problem with externalities, which put every economic actor in the uncomfortable position of having to sacrifice community interest for self-interest, or (perhaps less frequently) vice-versa. We all are driven by a mix of desires: to promote the community interest, and our own individual interest. This proposed system of incorporating external costs into the price of economic goods allows us to quickly and efficiently find a balance between self-interest and community interest, simply by seeking the lowest price for the things we buy, which we are naturally inclined to do already.
Is it plausible to think that we do not need radical transformation of society? Is it realistic to think that if we could just teach a few more people to stop dumping motor oil in the back alley, get the miles per gallon numbers up a bit more, get some more people to separate out their paper and glass and other recycleables, take their shopping bag with them for re-use, and such things, then we will have met the environmental challenges that confront us and achieved a sustainable society? I wonder what alternative proposals the reviewer would suggest that might have the potential for resolving the 'tragedy of the commons'. Or would he/she take issue with the suggestion that this proposal does that, or that the tragedy of the commons is an issue of concern?
This paradigm, by the way, does not only address environmental problems-- although ideas about how we might better address the problem of pollution did provide the germ that it grew from. This proposal also addresses problems of poverty and wealth disparity. It is hard to over-estimate, I think, the combined effect of both a completely free labor market, which gives everyone the greatest incentive to increase their knowledge, skills and abilities, and a guaranteed income, which protects all from abject poverty, which currently debilitates a large portion of humanity.
John Champagne
Systemic flaws are not reported
Summary: On the basis of an analogy between how nonhuman organisms (from unicellular to bees) affect and are affected by their environment and how economic forces affect the use of natural resources, this paper proposes a radical transformation of human life: Children are to be educated differently, governments as they now exist will be abolished, and the labor market will be liberated from its current constraints.
The detrimental impact human beings have on the environment presents us with the "greatest challenge" the species has faced since it began to walk and talk. Economics provides the key to its solution: a "resource fee" that will be assessed to every product and service. These fees will penalize the use of environmentally damaging things, providing the "feedback mechanism" that is needed so that human culture will be in touch with its impact on the biosphere. This fee will provide the marketplace with information about the product's or service's environmental impact. They will be determined democratically by every person on the planet. Proceeds will be used to support "things we would like to see more of."
Evaluation: This paper is eminently clear; the author is able in a few paragraphs to present and weave together findings from microbiology, ethology, and economics into an intriguing and intelligible picture. On the basis of his assessment of the current "environmental crisis," he proposes an interesting (and to me, novel) solution. An effective way of affecting people's behavior is through their wallets, so charge them for the damage they are indirectly doing to the environment. The author also recognizes a number of problems which might be raised to this suggestion (Who determines the fees?, How will this money be used?, Etc.) and attempts in the limited space available to address them. Although, as proposed, this suggestion seems to be thoroughly unrealistic, there could be merits to its basic idea. Something like a "resource fee" might be worth considering as environmental policies are discussed.
The significant "leftist" tendencies of the paper weaken it. The author continues to have hopes in a world (non-) government, a radical transformation of society, a radical and universal democracy, and an elimination or significant reduction of alienation. His solutions to the problems inherent in his proposal seem weak. It is not clear to me that all people (including children -- p.7, ln.20) can ever be in a position to assess the conflicting "findings" of the "experts" of interested parties as to the true environmental impact of every product and service of every activity of every person and company of the whole world. And, without governments, how will the money be spent? Will every person on the planet have a say? How could that occur?
Recommendation: If a clear and interesting voice from those who continue to propose radical transformations of society and of human nature is needed, this paper could find a place in the proceedings. If the volume needs to be limited to realistic proposals, it does not belong.
-- End of this anonymous critique --
Author's response:
The idea of a pollution fee or fee on use of natural resource, the commons, is not new with me. I learned about it in a college text during a course on political economy, in a book called, 'The Economics of Social Issues'. What is new, to my knowledge, is the connection drawn between this method of management of resources and the feedback mechanisms that operate in biological organisms, such as sensory nervous systems. Also new is the (proposed) practical realization of the idea that all people share in the ownership and management of the air and water, the commons, the natural resources, by receiving the proceeds of the user-fees, and by deciding what absolute limits will be placed on the use of the resources.
I do not propose that a fee be assessed on 'every product or service', but on those human actions which adversely impact the environment. If I am a reading tutor and I ask a student to read to me and I give little hints when needed, I am providing a service, but I am not adversely impacting the Commons, and would not expect to have to pay the people to compensate them for degrading a public resource. If I drive 50 miles to get to the school, I expect to pay a fee to compensate the people for degrading their resource, the air, but payment of this fee would not be a separate act. The fee would be incorporated in the price of fuel by the fact that extracting petroleum for use as fuel would have the appropriate fee attached. If I take some kind of waste products and recycle them into new product, I would not expect to have to pay a fee. " ... [C]harge them for the damage they are indirectly doing to the environment", sounds like we would examine each life, each person and make an assessment, a judgement of their impact on the earth by recording their purchases or examining their habits. That does sound totally unrealistic. But that is not what I propose. I would rather charge the corporations that damage the earth or cause environmental impacts. If individuals damage environmental health in ways that are not already accounted for in prices through this fee mechanism, then charge individuals for the damage they do directly.
As a practical matter, if a material is produced and marketed for a particular application, such as petroleum for fuel, then the producer ought to be assessed at the point of production as if delivery to market was equivalent to actual use. This way, the market will reflect in price the (perceived) ecologic impact of use. I would judge, for example, the 'damage to the earth' as the act of taking oil out of the ground, where it can be easily measured, rather than have gasoline delivered to the market prior to the assessment of any impact fees, and assessing the fees on the end-user. Making the necessary measurements as close to the point of production as possible will reduce the potential for subversion through black market trading.
It would be easier for me to accept 'unrealistic ... radical transformation' as valid and true argument against this paradigm if not for the fact that this plan could help to alleviate or eliminate some of our society's seemingly most intractable problems. This possibility of multiple benefits through the realization of this new paradigm could overcome the resistance to change that usually makes radical change such an unrealistic possibility. If not now for radical transformation, when? We have just invented a whole new media: Interactive hypermedia; the internet. Perhaps soon, this new form of human communication will be as extensive as the telephone network, which also continues to expand. We are in the midst of a long period of accelerating change. It is in times of invention of new tools that we see the greatest social, political and economic changes, because they so affect the ways that human beings interact with one another.
The basic idea here, or basic ideas are that we all own the air and water and natural resources, and to the extent that any person or corporate entity appropriates any of these resources for their own use, that entity ought to compensate the owners of the resource, the people at large. The monies paid in exchange for the use of resources should be controlled by the people, who may use these funds for whatever purpose they choose, but perhaps with a portion dedicated to community projects that enjoy the support of a large majority of citizens, and the remaining portion available for individual needs and wants. The people also should control the level of the fee, or the overall rate of resource use: The people are owners and managers of the commons.
"Something like a resource fee..." What does this mean? What thing like a resource fee might we consider? How would this something be like a resource fee and how would it be different? (Who would decide on the fee amount? How would the proceeds be spent?)
What is meant by 'leftist' tendencies, and why is it in quotes? (I did not use the term in the paper.) Perhaps 'leftist' refers to the idea that all the people own and would help manage the commons, and would receive the proceeds of the fees charged against their use. Anecdotal evidence suggests that this idea is readily understood and accepted by members of the public who have been apprised of it. Many people feel that, yes, this is a good idea, but 'they', the established interests, will never go for it. To the extent that politicians, captains of industry and citizens successfully turn the purposes of government and corporate institutions toward these ends, they can help restore a sense of integrity and efficacy to our public institutions. This idea, put in practice, would reverse the trend toward greater disparity of wealth, while preserving, even improving, free market rewards of individual effort and initiative. It would help to promote a sense among the populace that we all share a power and responsibility to be good stewards of the earth. For these reasons, 'leftist' tendencies seems to be not a weakness, but a strength.
I did not intend to suggest that children would be responsible for making decisions regarding resource use. I do suggest though, that children, students, might be involved in the process of gathering information about the opinions of the adults in their neighborhood. But the reviewer's statement brings to mind the idea that some communities might choose to celebrate exceptional, exemplary schools that cast their own mock votes about what environmental impacts ought to be allowed with such careful consideration and clear explication of the why behind their votes that they stand as a model to others of how this responsibility for stewardship of the commons might be carried out. The community might want the school's mock votes published so that they can be copied by others, in effect letting the adults delegate their vote to those outstanding students.
We could ask someone from a trusted accounting firm (or someone who knows more about accounting principles than I) how we might make scalable structures, accounts of each person's preferences, then each community's preferences, etc. that could be surveyed at any level, just as search engines survey large amounts of data through a network. The example of the school above may offer a clue to how this might be done. If teachers and students made it their business to ask community members what their opinions are about conditions in the community, they could post the results of their surveys on the internet for all to see. To the extent that the expressed wishes of the people conflict with actual conditions, we would expect resource user-fees to rise or fall as appropriate, until the disparity is resolved.
What better time to consider and make radical transformations than now? These are times of rapid, accelerating change, when the situation is dynamic and plastic, when we can make a great difference for the future depending on what decisions we take today, what we do today. A radical transformation, in the right direction, could be a very helpful and timely change.
But what change in human nature does the reviewer believe is required by this proposal? If anything, this paradigm is more respectful, more accepting of human nature as it is. The current system has a problem with externalities, which put every economic actor in the uncomfortable position of having to sacrifice community interest for self-interest, or (perhaps less frequently) vice-versa. We all are driven by a mix of desires: to promote the community interest, and our own individual interest. This proposed system of incorporating external costs into the price of economic goods allows us to quickly and efficiently find a balance between self-interest and community interest, simply by seeking the lowest price for the things we buy, which we are naturally inclined to do already.
Is it plausible to think that we do not need radical transformation of society? Is it realistic to think that if we could just teach a few more people to stop dumping motor oil in the back alley, get the miles per gallon numbers up a bit more, get some more people to separate out their paper and glass and other recycleables, take their shopping bag with them for re-use, and such things, then we will have met the environmental challenges that confront us and achieved a sustainable society? I wonder what alternative proposals the reviewer would suggest that might have the potential for resolving the 'tragedy of the commons'. Or would he/she take issue with the suggestion that this proposal does that, or that the tragedy of the commons is an issue of concern?
This paradigm, by the way, does not only address environmental problems-- although ideas about how we might better address the problem of pollution did provide the germ that it grew from. This proposal also addresses problems of poverty and wealth disparity. It is hard to over-estimate, I think, the combined effect of both a completely free labor market, which gives everyone the greatest incentive to increase their knowledge, skills and abilities, and a guaranteed income, which protects all from abject poverty, which currently debilitates a large portion of humanity.
John Champagne
Systemic flaws are not reported
Thursday, October 18, 2012
Natural Law remedy for systemic flaw: Civilization can be made sustainable and equitable
An unsustainable civilization is a consequence of a systemic flaw -- Natural law points to a solution.
Presently, our system of government does not embody all natural rights in its functioning. The idea that natural wealth (what we might call commons or public property) ought to be shared equally is reflected in the writings of Thomas Hobbes, John Locke, John Stuart Mill, Thomas Paine, Adam Smith and others. Yet our society does not manifest this idea in practice. Natural wealth (or a monetary representation of that wealth) is not shared. Rates of putting pollution and depleting resources are not being held to limits acceptable to most people. We lack even a basic public interest poll to discern what most people would find acceptable regarding various kinds of impact on the environment.
This systemic flaw, this failure to embody a basic moral precept in practice, means that harm is done to the environment by industries without a direct and proportional economic cost being incurred. A consequence of this moral defect is that prices of things do not reflect environmental impacts such as pollution, resource depletion and habitat destruction. Prices lie to us about true costs, so we make bad decisions directly related to what kind of harmful impact is being hidden. A visceral example of this is the intense crowding of animals in what is sometimes called the 'animal exploitation industry': By crowding animals together more and by feeding antibiotics to them, expenses can be reduced and profits increased, but at potentially very high cost: More crowding means more stress and suffering of animals held captive; Routine use of antibiotics means more rapid loss of effectiveness of antibiotics to fight disease in human beings, as pathogenic bacteria are given abundant opportunity to develop resistance.
The environment is more polluted and antibiotic resistance develops faster because industries are allowed to externalize their costs. These adverse impacts--the costs imposed on society and on animal captives--are not reflected in prices.
Living systems, including human society, are delicate, intricate phenomena. It is always easier to tear down and destroy than it is to build and create. This reflects the nature of the underlying enabling conditions that are necessary in order for any creative or developmental process to unfold. The conditions necessary for maintenance of a healthy society require order and structure rather than chaos or randomness. This is true whether we are talking about creating a tower of blocks, a work of art or a civilization.
A civilization is stronger and more resilient when most everyone believes that we will all be better off by working to improve on what we have made. We cannot have many people wanting to destroy this nascent global civilization to see what else might take its place. For the benefit of all, there must be very few of us who believe that the world we have created is ugly or hurtful or evil. We need a society that all can believe in and feel glad to be a part of. Among other things, this means that the rules we live by must be seen as fair. It also means that we must have a system that recognizes the people as the rightful owners of natural resource wealth, so that the world we create together will not be a world that has more paving or pollution or noise or extraction of limited resources than what most people would say is acceptable. Then we will have a true democracy.
If we limit or discourage excessive taking of resources... or putting of pollution... or degradation of our view of the stars from outdoor lighting... by charging a fee to offending industries, then the fee proceeds (a monetary representation of what we all own in common) could be shared equally among all the world's people. (A system of random polls can show us when we have reached a point where impacts that had been excessive have been brought into line with what most people think is acceptable. At that point, the associated fees will be set at the right amount.) We will have a more equitable society. No one would live in abject poverty.
Equal sharing of natural wealth cures the defect that we see in the thriving and collapse of civilization. It also makes the boom and bust business 'cycle' into a less wildly gyrating phenomenon.
Biological Model for Politics and Economics: Human Society as Neural Network
We can think of human rights as natural law of social interaction. If human rights are a kind of natural law, then basic claims that citizens might make (such as a claim to a right to share in deciding limits to pollution and limits to rates of taking of natural resources) can be seen as manifestations of a natural phenomenon. Citizens must assert their claims to natural rights, and must act so as to create systems of government that assure these rights are respected in practice, to ensure the healthy functioning of society.
Presently, our system of government does not embody all natural rights in its functioning. The idea that natural wealth (what we might call commons or public property) ought to be shared equally is reflected in the writings of Thomas Hobbes, John Locke, John Stuart Mill, Thomas Paine, Adam Smith and others. Yet our society does not manifest this idea in practice. Natural wealth (or a monetary representation of that wealth) is not shared. Rates of putting pollution and depleting resources are not being held to limits acceptable to most people. We lack even a basic public interest poll to discern what most people would find acceptable regarding various kinds of impact on the environment.
This systemic flaw, this failure to embody a basic moral precept in practice, means that harm is done to the environment by industries without a direct and proportional economic cost being incurred. A consequence of this moral defect is that prices of things do not reflect environmental impacts such as pollution, resource depletion and habitat destruction. Prices lie to us about true costs, so we make bad decisions directly related to what kind of harmful impact is being hidden. A visceral example of this is the intense crowding of animals in what is sometimes called the 'animal exploitation industry': By crowding animals together more and by feeding antibiotics to them, expenses can be reduced and profits increased, but at potentially very high cost: More crowding means more stress and suffering of animals held captive; Routine use of antibiotics means more rapid loss of effectiveness of antibiotics to fight disease in human beings, as pathogenic bacteria are given abundant opportunity to develop resistance.
The environment is more polluted and antibiotic resistance develops faster because industries are allowed to externalize their costs. These adverse impacts--the costs imposed on society and on animal captives--are not reflected in prices.
Living systems, including human society, are delicate, intricate phenomena. It is always easier to tear down and destroy than it is to build and create. This reflects the nature of the underlying enabling conditions that are necessary in order for any creative or developmental process to unfold. The conditions necessary for maintenance of a healthy society require order and structure rather than chaos or randomness. This is true whether we are talking about creating a tower of blocks, a work of art or a civilization.
A civilization is stronger and more resilient when most everyone believes that we will all be better off by working to improve on what we have made. We cannot have many people wanting to destroy this nascent global civilization to see what else might take its place. For the benefit of all, there must be very few of us who believe that the world we have created is ugly or hurtful or evil. We need a society that all can believe in and feel glad to be a part of. Among other things, this means that the rules we live by must be seen as fair. It also means that we must have a system that recognizes the people as the rightful owners of natural resource wealth, so that the world we create together will not be a world that has more paving or pollution or noise or extraction of limited resources than what most people would say is acceptable. Then we will have a true democracy.
If we limit or discourage excessive taking of resources... or putting of pollution... or degradation of our view of the stars from outdoor lighting... by charging a fee to offending industries, then the fee proceeds (a monetary representation of what we all own in common) could be shared equally among all the world's people. (A system of random polls can show us when we have reached a point where impacts that had been excessive have been brought into line with what most people think is acceptable. At that point, the associated fees will be set at the right amount.) We will have a more equitable society. No one would live in abject poverty.
Equal sharing of natural wealth cures the defect that we see in the thriving and collapse of civilization. It also makes the boom and bust business 'cycle' into a less wildly gyrating phenomenon.
Biological Model for Politics and Economics: Human Society as Neural Network
Friday, October 12, 2012
Moral foundation allows us to adapt to circumstances
Our global civilization is headed for another great collapse unless we bring our behavior more into accord with our principles.
Natural resources belong to all. They should be shared.
Intelligence is the ability to make connections that foster adaptive responses, to preserve the life and promote the health of an organism. Intelligent societies respond to environmental conditions in ways that promote sustainability. Societies lack intelligence if actions by members cause damage that is not readily apparent to those members. Then individuals may unknowingly do things that harm the interests of all members of society, and that may even cause harm to the larger community of life. When we do things that cause harm and cannot see the effect of our actions, we cannot respond in a way so as to reduce or stop the harm. We cannot consider the effects of our actions on others if we remain unaware of those effects. We are unable to abide by the basic moral precept that demands that we not do to others that which we would not have done to ourselves.
Economists call the disconnect between what it costs to produce things on the one hand (including costs in terms of pollution and resource depletion) and the prices of products offered in the market on the other hand 'externalities'. Fees charged to industries according to how much ecological damage they cause would make prices of things reflect the harm (the costs) that otherwise would remain hidden from consumers. A democratic society would set the fees so that they are just high enough to make industries try hard enough to reduce pollution, resource depletion and other harmful environmental impacts. We will know that industries are, in fact, trying hard enough for a particular kind of impact when most people in a random poll agree that the amount of that kind of impact currently being produced is acceptable, with a good balance being struck between freedom and constraint, so that our economic system can function and human needs can be met on the one hand, and the interests of future generations and the larger living community are protected on the other hand.
We could decide that it will serve the public interest to limit the rate of taking of natural resources (by applying a fee), so that the shock of having to adapt to the scarcity of resources can be reduced by spreading resource availability out over a longer timeframe; or so that, in the case of renewable resources, a sustainable and healthy resource base can be maintained.
We could decide, collectively (by means of a random poll), that it is in the interest of stargazers (that's most of us from time to time) to dim our outdoor lighting somewhat on a regular basis, so that we might enjoy a better view of the night sky. Perhaps we would want to further reduce outdoor lighting on select nights, to avoid disorienting night-migrating birds, perhaps, or so that we might more fully appreciate occasional meteor showers, thin crescent (blue) moons and passing comets. A system of fees on outdoor lighting could achieve this. The fees would float up or down, if there were an imbalance between the number of people who want more outdoor lighting vs. the number who want less. Lighting fixtures could be designed to automatically dim or shut off when the fee reached a threshold amount, as determined by the user. Small changes in opinion about acceptable levels of light pollution (or any other environmental impact) would translate to modest but real changes in actual conditions. The reality, the actual human impacts on the Earth would come to match what most people feel is most acceptable. When the reality matches what the people want, then we can say we live in a democracy.
Outdoor lighting is but one of the many kinds of impacts on the environment that human beings must limit, in an efficient and fair way, if we are to build a global society that is sustainable and consistent with democratic principles. The fee system could result in the world that the largest number of people say they want to live in. We would have a more democratic society. When prices show us the harmful effect on the environment of what we do, we will choose the more environmentally-friendly habits and practices. Honest prices will promote sustainability.
John Champagne
@TallPhilosopher
Equal sharing of natural wealth promotes justice and sustainability: A solution to the matter of instability we know as the 'arc of civilization' (thrive and collapse)
Biological Model for Politics and Economics
Prices should honestly represent costs.
Natural resources belong to all. They should be shared.
Intelligence is the ability to make connections that foster adaptive responses, to preserve the life and promote the health of an organism. Intelligent societies respond to environmental conditions in ways that promote sustainability. Societies lack intelligence if actions by members cause damage that is not readily apparent to those members. Then individuals may unknowingly do things that harm the interests of all members of society, and that may even cause harm to the larger community of life. When we do things that cause harm and cannot see the effect of our actions, we cannot respond in a way so as to reduce or stop the harm. We cannot consider the effects of our actions on others if we remain unaware of those effects. We are unable to abide by the basic moral precept that demands that we not do to others that which we would not have done to ourselves.
Economists call the disconnect between what it costs to produce things on the one hand (including costs in terms of pollution and resource depletion) and the prices of products offered in the market on the other hand 'externalities'. Fees charged to industries according to how much ecological damage they cause would make prices of things reflect the harm (the costs) that otherwise would remain hidden from consumers. A democratic society would set the fees so that they are just high enough to make industries try hard enough to reduce pollution, resource depletion and other harmful environmental impacts. We will know that industries are, in fact, trying hard enough for a particular kind of impact when most people in a random poll agree that the amount of that kind of impact currently being produced is acceptable, with a good balance being struck between freedom and constraint, so that our economic system can function and human needs can be met on the one hand, and the interests of future generations and the larger living community are protected on the other hand.
We could decide that it will serve the public interest to limit the rate of taking of natural resources (by applying a fee), so that the shock of having to adapt to the scarcity of resources can be reduced by spreading resource availability out over a longer timeframe; or so that, in the case of renewable resources, a sustainable and healthy resource base can be maintained.
We could decide, collectively (by means of a random poll), that it is in the interest of stargazers (that's most of us from time to time) to dim our outdoor lighting somewhat on a regular basis, so that we might enjoy a better view of the night sky. Perhaps we would want to further reduce outdoor lighting on select nights, to avoid disorienting night-migrating birds, perhaps, or so that we might more fully appreciate occasional meteor showers, thin crescent (blue) moons and passing comets. A system of fees on outdoor lighting could achieve this. The fees would float up or down, if there were an imbalance between the number of people who want more outdoor lighting vs. the number who want less. Lighting fixtures could be designed to automatically dim or shut off when the fee reached a threshold amount, as determined by the user. Small changes in opinion about acceptable levels of light pollution (or any other environmental impact) would translate to modest but real changes in actual conditions. The reality, the actual human impacts on the Earth would come to match what most people feel is most acceptable. When the reality matches what the people want, then we can say we live in a democracy.
Outdoor lighting is but one of the many kinds of impacts on the environment that human beings must limit, in an efficient and fair way, if we are to build a global society that is sustainable and consistent with democratic principles. The fee system could result in the world that the largest number of people say they want to live in. We would have a more democratic society. When prices show us the harmful effect on the environment of what we do, we will choose the more environmentally-friendly habits and practices. Honest prices will promote sustainability.
John Champagne
@TallPhilosopher
Equal sharing of natural wealth promotes justice and sustainability: A solution to the matter of instability we know as the 'arc of civilization' (thrive and collapse)
Biological Model for Politics and Economics
Wednesday, September 26, 2012
Minimum Wage vs. Minimum Income
Equal ownership of natural resource wealth will promote economic justice and sustainability.
Minimum wage laws distract us from a conversation about minimum income.
If we look beyond questions of air and water quality and
minerals management, we can see that this policy of charging a fee
or rent to
those who cause adverse environmental
impacts could be applied to the management of other commons resources. The
number and diversity of fish in the sea is decreasing. We could attach a fee to
the taking of those species that are threatened with depletion. We could attach
VERY HIGH fees to the taking or killing of any member of a species that we do
not want anyone to take, so that no one will see that activity as profitable.
What we should do can be determined by a random poll. If most people surveyed say that rates of taking this or that kind of fish from the ocean should be reduced, then permit prices for that type of fishing could be raised. Surveys can ask what percent change would be best, so that the average of all responses can tell us how much we should reduce (or increase) a particular kind of environmental impact. (Many people will not have an informed opinion, but if the method of polling allows some time for research before a reply is expected, respondents could look to see what others who are more informed have to say on the topic. This system will effectively delegate decisions to those experts who are most trusted by the people.)
Maybe someday the power to
decide these questions (and others) will be vested in the people. This power will
be in the hands of the people if we care to shape our society toward these
ends. If we say that this is the world--if we
say that this is the democratic society--that we want to make.
Equal Sharing of Natural Resources Promotes Justice and Sustainability.
More security for the least secure means more security for all:
- A Capitalism-Communism Synthesis
More security for the least secure means more security for all - Shorter, older version
Minimum wage laws distract us from a conversation about minimum income.
Minimum wage laws appear to help those who have jobs that
pay near the defined minimum level. Such laws also help those who make and sell
machinery that replaces low-skilled workers. Minimum wage laws do not
help those who might earn below the legally-defined limit but who have not yet
developed skills or experience sufficient to garner a higher wage. Minimum wage
laws harm everyone if the rising cost of labor causes employers to choose a
method of achieving their goals that
leads to more pollution or more rapid depletion of natural resources than what an alternative, more labor-intensive method would cause.
We cannot create wealth through legislation. But we can alleviate poverty by ending the
current practice of allowing theft of natural resources from the people. We all
own the air and water. We all have an equal right to use the air and
water and to say what the limits on pollution levels should be. We also
have an equal right
to access the shared mineral wealth of Earth, and a right to share
in deciding overall limits to the rates of taking of resources. (Some people
may recognize these basic rights as a function of natural law, while others may
see our right to breathe air and drink water as flowing from God's grace, but
these different views may not be mutually exclusive. In any case, we have a corresponding duty to create a political system that ensures that equal claims to air and
water and other natural wealth are respected in practice.)
We could attach fees to the taking of resources and the
release of pollution. This would allow us to measure the value of natural resources and
services used by industry in pursuit of profit, and it would discourage
unwanted and potentially harmful environmental impacts. We could adjust the
fees to whatever level necessary to ensure that only the amount of pollution and rate of resource extraction that the people deem
permissible will be deemed profitable by industry. (Industries would not be able to afford to pollute so much
as the cost of doing so increased. The most polluting industries would
shrink. All industries would strive to reduce their impacts on the environment.) The fee proceeds could (and should) be shared
among all people--or all adults--equally. [The portion of natural wealth that belongs to the youngest members of the community (who are too young to know how best to spend their money) could be used to fund schools, public health programs, public parks, museums, perhaps, that will contribute to the wellbeing of society (and will benefit those children) for years to come.]
Proceeds from environmental impact fees would be a monetary representation of
the value of resources owned by all but taken by industry in pursuit of profit.
Public policy should assure not a minimum wage, but a minimum income.
When all people have some income separate from work income, all workers will have greater latitude to decide what work they want to do. Those with fewer skills will realize the greatest benefit when (an economic measure of) natural wealth is shared equally, because they are generally in the most precarious economic position.
What we should do can be determined by a random poll. If most people surveyed say that rates of taking this or that kind of fish from the ocean should be reduced, then permit prices for that type of fishing could be raised. Surveys can ask what percent change would be best, so that the average of all responses can tell us how much we should reduce (or increase) a particular kind of environmental impact. (Many people will not have an informed opinion, but if the method of polling allows some time for research before a reply is expected, respondents could look to see what others who are more informed have to say on the topic. This system will effectively delegate decisions to those experts who are most trusted by the people.)
Biodiversity is being lost at a truly astounding rate.
Considering the current rates of desertification and loss of topsoil;
considering the pace of forest destruction, the speed of encroachment on and
paving of wilderness areas, the increasing threats to coral reefs, and our
ongoing assault on climate stability; one might wonder whether we even care
what kind of world we will leave for our children. If we were to decide that
protecting biodiversity and promoting ecosystem health are worthy public policy
goals, we could charge a fee for any land use that disturbs wildlife habitat or
decreases biodiversity, from
monoculture to asphalt. The fee could be greater for those activities
that produce more harmful impacts on the Earth or that are more disruptive of
ecosystems.
With citizens voting (through random-sample surveys) on
whether the amount of paving, rates of taking of resources, levels of
pollution, etc., are acceptable or should be higher or lower, we would have
a system wherein we could all share in sculpting the overall human impacts on Earth. We would shape the world to match what we want it to be. Our economy would function in a way
that would achieve a balance between supply of and demand for produced
goods and services, AND it would achieve an appropriate balance, as defined by
the people, between the need to conserve natural resources, preserve
environmental quality and promote ecosystem health on the one hand, and the
convenience and necessity of availing ourselves of natural resource wealth in
pursuit of human goals on the other hand.
The amount of money collected through fees on the release of pollution, the taking of resources and destruction of habitat would be substantial. We may not be
able to afford to adopt such a system while also keeping the current system of
taxes on income and sales. We may want to eliminate those taxes, or substantially reduce them. (Some sales tax
might be appropriate, to cover the cost of policing the marketplace, for
example.) We could fund community
services from the various environmental impact fees. The proceeds from resource
user-fees could be shared among all people equally. Each of us could spend an
agreed-upon fraction (perhaps half) on community needs (e.g.: libraries,
schools, public health, police and fire protection, etc.) and spend the
remainder to meet our own personal needs. We would all share in creating the
kind of social environment that we would choose. We would share, in a more
direct and obvious way, decisions about what our community priorities should
be. And no one would live in abject poverty.
This paradigm sees the role of government as an arbiter
between the individual and community. It recognizes no authority of government
to initiate
the use of force against citizens. Only those actions (by individuals or
corporate entities) that adversely affect others would come within the purview
of government. In fact, government per
se would not exist as we know it. Many of the decisions of
government would be dispersed, decentralized, vested in all the people. This
"public realm only" focus for government action is an important point
because a profound change in the political culture cannot occur except through
the active support of the people.
Many people subscribe to the libertarian view that the
government ought not initiate the use of force against peaceful citizens.
Libertarians will likely embrace this alternative paradigm if they believe that
it appropriately draws the line between regulated or restricted actions (those
that adversely impact others or the community) on the one hand, and actions
which are the free choice of individuals (private behavior) on the other hand.
Some people believe that the prevalence of outdoor
advertising signs and billboards is too high to allow for an aesthetically
pleasing visual landscape. Is the prevalence of outdoor lighting so great that
our ability to see the stars has become
too-severely diminished?
We may want to adopt a few "lights out" nights,
to remind ourselves that there are stars out there. If enough people want this
to happen and demand that industries account for their side-effect costs, then
this vision can be borne out in reality.
More security for the least secure means more security for all:
- A Capitalism-Communism Synthesis
More security for the least secure means more security for all - Shorter, older version
Subscribe to:
Posts (Atom)